Previously,
I have focused on analyzing Kazakh data strictly along provincial lines
(fourteen oblasts and the two cities of Astana and Almaty). However, crossing
provincial boundaries are regional ethnic ties that permeate Kazakh politics
and are generally classified at their broadest levels as Hordes or zhuz (жүз). Often referred to as tribes, these confederations
are divided into the Great (Ұлы жүз),
Middle (Орта жүз), and Junior (Кiшi жүз). Each zhuz is sub-divided further into groups
usually denoted as “clans”, with further sub-divisions down to individual
lineages. The significance of these
associations within the heavily clientelist politics of Kazakhstan could be
influential in my analysis of human trafficking risk within the provinces. As I
discussed in previous posts, individuals become more susceptible to human
traffickers if they face a severe lack of opportunity in their home region. Particularly
young people, with little social or employment prospects at home, are more
likely to take risky jobs abroad that can ensnare them in foreign trafficking
rings, or engage in other risky behavior domestically such as drug trafficking
or prostitution. Patron-client networks in Kazakhstan may favor members of one zhuz over another based on access to officials
in power, and if so this could have a considerable impact on available
opportunities and resources to members of a zhuz without
powerful patrons.
Schatz (2000, 2005) provides an informative account
of the resurgence of clan politics following independence in Kazakhstan,
and the role the zhuz play today.
Despite the professed push for erasing class distinctions in the Soviet Union,
individual Kazakh identification with their historical zhuz was not eliminated. Instead, these identities became crucial
in an era of scarcity under the Communist system. Individuals relied on
familial networks to not only secure good positions, but also to obtain basic goods
and services. Into modern times, the near universal possession of extensive
individual genealogical knowledge created easily accessible, and manipulatable,
identifiers for members to connect with one another. The average Kazakh is
expected to accurately know and be able to orally trace their genealogical lineage
going back to at least the seventh generation. Following the collapse of the Soviet
Union, early elite efforts at nation-building utilized these ethnic identities
to increase a societal sense of “Kazakhness” independent of their Soviet past,
and to build their own individual power bases for political gain. Elites used
their lineage connections to establish a link with as many supporters as
possible, over time this became “a virtual bidding war” that pushed these ethnic
markers to the forefront of Kazakh politics (Schatz, 2005). Despite early elite
intentions to build a unifying Kazakh identity by encouraging Kazakhs to embrace
their zhuz, the exploitation of these
associations by elites heavily politicized these identifications and polarized society along zhuz and clan lines. As
political elites ascended into power and maintained their positions based on
these associations, they grew increasingly more salient as the spoils and
rewards of office were increasingly limited to members of the zhuz in power.
Post-independence, zhuz and clan distinctions have become intrinsically tied to power
and goods distribution. To gain access to lucrative posts in state bureaucracy
that provide access to rents from the extractive industries, elites continue to
rely on their clan connections, and distribute the spoils to their key
supporters in this patron-client system. Local elites push their kin-based
connections to potential supporters, and emphasize the likely benefits to be
received in reward for support, and the need for clan-based loyalty to protect
members from the aspirations of competing clans. President Nazarbaev and his
family are a prime example. At the center of power for the entirety of Kazakhstan’s
independence, he has been in a prime position to privilege both family members
and his fellow members of the Great zhuz.
A pattern of political appointments and key contracts by him have tended to
favor extended family and core members of his zhuz. However, Nazarbaev’s core concern of preventing any
regionalist movements built on excluded clan loyalties that might challenge
national integrity and his hold on power, led to a policy of clan balancing
within the provinces that to a degree has worked to push the clan out of regional politics. Given the strength of their position, provincial
governors have been rotated regularly to prevent any from building a rival
power base. Few served longer than two years in office before being moved to
other state posts.
Despite Nazarbaev’s intentions, clan association is
still a crucial political factor at the regional level. Governors are usually
from whatever clan is dominant in the region. Schatz (2005) provides an
example:
“Most found it hard to
imagine a situation in which, for example, the governor of Atyrau region could
be a non-Zhetiru or the governor of South Kazakhstan region could be a
non-Dulat.”
Upon assuming power,
governors often quickly moved to reward their supporters and fill the
bureaucracy with loyalists (Schatz, 2005):
“For example, upon
assuming office in 1995 the governor of Zhambyl region removed 140 employees,
replacing 80% of them with members of the Zhanys subdivision of the Dulat
division (Great zhuz clan). In Torghai
region the new governor promoted the members of his clan Zhoghary-Shekty of the
Arghyn division (Middle zhuz), at the
expense of traditionally predominant Uzyn and Qulan-Qypshaq subdivisions (also
Middle zhuz). In the South Kazakhstan
region, local subethnic patronage networks ensnared members of the lucrative
extractive industries, who had a stake in the region’s oil refinery.”
It was difficult for
governors from non-local clans to succeed, as sub-par performance was instantly
ascribed to their clan association, and support would vanish quickly.
Schatz
(2005) provides an analysis of the respective positions of the three zhuz both
within the elite population and within state bureaucracy, and how these
positions have evolved since independence. He only looks at rural-born elite as zhuz
identification is the easiest to identify for Kazakhs from rural portions
of the country, where zhuz membership
is still geographically associated. His analysis has shown that over time, the
Great zhuz has consistently been
disproportionately represented in state bureaucracy compared to their
demographic position, with the Junior zhuz
continually relegated to the weakest position. The Junior zhuz has been historically excluded from
powerful positions, which could be partially attributable to the physical distance
between Junior power centers in the west of the country and the Soviet-era
capital of Almaty (a map illustrating the general location of the zhuz and their clans is included at the bottom). Great and Middle zhuz
members have also been generally better educated and trained since the Soviet
period. Although initially excluded to some degree from power, the Middle zhuz has been pulled into an alliance
with the Great zhuz, as illustrated
by the relocation of the capital city from Almaty in Great zhuz territory, to Astana in Middle zhuz territory, and significant incorporation of Middle zhuz members into state power
structures. The following graphs provided by Shatz (2005) illustrate the
disproportionate representation of the Great and Middle zhuz in the Kazakh elite (Table 2), and the shift in zhuz representation after the alliance
between the Great (also referred to as Elder) and Middle zhuz (Tables 3 and 4).
Schatz, Edward. 2000. “The Politics of Multiple Identities:
Lineage and Ethnicity in Kazakhstan.” Europe-Asia
Studies 52(3): 489-506
Schatz, Edward. 2005. “Reconceptualizing Clans: Kinship
Networks and Statehood in Kazakhstan.” Nationalities
Papers 33(2)
No comments:
Post a Comment